International Journal of Urban and Regional Research

International Journal of Urban and Regional Research Volume 26.3 September 2002 531–54
Global and World Cities: A View from off the
Map*
JENNIFER ROBINSON
There are a large number of cities around the world which do not register on intellectual maps that chart
the rise and fall of global and world cities. They don’t fall into either of these categories, and they probably
never will — but many managers of these cities would like them to. Some of these cities find themselves
interpreted instead through the lens of developmentalism, an approach which broadly understands these
places to be lacking in the qualities of city-ness, and which is concerned to improve capacities of
governance, service provision and productivity. Such an approach supports some of the more alarmist
responses to mega-cities, which are more commonly identified in poorer countries. But for many smaller
cities, even the category mega-city is irrelevant. My concerns in this article extend beyond the poor fit of
these popular categories, though. I would like to suggest that these widely circulating approaches to
contemporary urbanization — global and world cities, together with the persistent use of the category
‘third-world city’ — impose substantial limitations on imagining or planning the futures of cities around the
world.
Part of the adverse worldly impact of these urban theories is, I argue, a consequence of the geographical
division of urban studies between urban theory, broadly focused on the West, and development studies,
focused on places that were once called ‘third-world cities’. This division might simply be an innocent
acknowledgement of difference (Szelenyi, 1996). However, apart from the value-laden historical meaning
of these
categorical ascriptions, the persistent alignment of a ‘theory’/‘development’ dualism with 1
the ‘West’/‘third world’ division in urban studies, suggests otherwise. One of the consequences of these
overlapping dualisms, is that understandings of city-ness have come to rest on the (usually unstated)
experiences of a relatively small group of (mostly western) cities, and cities outside of the West are
assessed in terms of this pre-given
* I should like to thank people who attended various seminars where early versions of this article were presented — at Birmingham,
Loughborough and Kings College London Geography Departments; at the OU- Bristol-Durham Cities Seminars, the 2000 AAG and
the Urban Futures Conference in Johannesburg. All the discussions made me think harder about these points and improved the
article, as did the individual comments of Richard Tomlinson, Steve Pile, Robert Beauregard and the journal’s anonymous referees. I
would also like to thank students at the LSE who sat through very anxious presentations of a course I had been asked to give on
‘Third World Urbanization’, but who luckily seemed to be far more comfortable with this categorization than their teacher! Various
people commented on other papers which helped a lot with the focus for this one: Kevin Cox, Edgar Pieterse, Maliq Simone, and the
OU course teams for DD304 and U213. Thank you!
1 This argument would seem to hold also for other cities ‘beyond the West’, such as post-Socialist cities (Andrusz et al., 1996).
World city theorists now frequently assign cities in former socialist countries to a separate ‘exceptional’ category, associating their
globalization with the privatization of former national services and industries (Beaverstock et al., 1999; Taylor, 2000).
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002. Published by Blackwell Publishers, 108 Cowley Road, Oxford OX4 1JF, UK and 350 Main Street,
Malden, MA 02148, USA.
532 Jennifer Robinson
standard of (world) city-ness, or urban economic dynamism. This article explores the extent to which
more recent global and world city approaches, although enthusiastic about tracking transnational
processes, have nonetheless reproduced this long-standing division within urban studies.
As part of an effort to promote a more cosmopolitan approach to urban studies, I want to trace some
paths across this entrenched division between theory and development. I do this by reflecting on some
fashionable approaches to cities from a position off their maps. Of course, the cities I am concerned with
are most emphatically on the map of a broad range of diverse global political, economic and cultural
connections, but this is frequently discounted and certainly never explored within these theoretical
approaches. There is a need to construct (or promote) an alternative urban theory which reflects the
experiences of a much wider range of cities. This will involve disrupting the narrow vision of a (still)
somewhat imperialist approach to cities, which has been reinforced by the strident economism in
accounts of global and world cities (Smith, 2001). Elements of urban theory have become transfixed with
the apparent success and dynamism of certain stylish sectors of the global economy, despite (and
perhaps because of) their circumscribed geographical purchase and most unappealing consequences.
These studies have been valuable, and offer great insight into the limited part of the world and economy
that they study. My suggestion, though, is that these insights could be incorporated in a broader and less
ambitious approach to cities around the world, an approach without categories and more inclusive of the
diversity of experience in ordinary cities.
After reviewing some of the effects of global and world city approaches from a viewpoint off their maps, I
draw attention to some alternative approaches to different cities. Moving beyond comparative studies
(which are a good starting point), I suggest that recent efforts to propose an account of ‘ordinary cities’
(Amin and Graham, 1997) offer an as yet unrecognized opportunity to develop a more cosmopolitan
account of city- ness. By this I mean to build on James Clifford’s (1997) idea of ‘discrepant
cosmopolitanisms’, rather than a universalizing or homogenizing cosmopolitan impulse (see Cheah and
Robbins, 1998). Clifford’s interest is in delocalizing professional anthropology, partly by insisting that
cultures are not (only) localized and that the village- based ethnography is a limited and misleading
research tool (see also Gupta and Ferguson, 1999). Connections and travels beyond the local are
long-standing and constitutive of local cultures all over the world: an important consideration for any urban
scholar (Smith, 2001). But, importantly for this article, he also wants to encourage anthropologists to
consider the trajectories of their own practices and analyses. Urbanists, too, could find it valuable to think
about the contrast between the restricted spatialities of their theories — the geography of urban theory —
and the diverse cosmopolitanisms of the cities they write about.
My primary concern, then, is with the persistence of a split between accounts of cities in countries which
have been labelled ‘third world’ and those in the ‘West’. Put simply, the segregation is between cities
which are captured through the rubric of
2
‘developmentalism’ (not [yet] cities ) and cities which are thought through to produce
(un/located) theory. My contention is that ‘urban theory’ is based primarily on the experiences and
histories of western cities — much as Chakrabarty (2000) suggests that the theories and categories of
historical scholarship have been rooted both in western experiences and their intellectual traditions. And,
like him, I want to suggest that restructuring the terrain on which different kinds of cities are thought within
urban studies could enhance the understanding of cities everywhere. Many writers on cities outside the
‘West’ continue to complain that urban ‘theory’ has a restricted purchase — with the cry that ‘Western
theories of urbanization are not relevant here’ — in Cairo, or the
2 Here we might find comparison with the dynamic Homi Bhabha (1994) discusses in the relation between colonizer and colonized,
under the rubric — not quite/not white.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 533
Philippines, Malaysia or Jakarta (for example, Kelly, 1999; McGee, 1995; Dick and Rimmer, 1998;
Stewart, 1999). This seems to imply that these cities are ‘different’, that they belong in a different
category. Alternatively, it could confirm my point that existing
‘theory’ is located elsewhere — it is not developed in relation to the experiences and 3
trajectories of these cities. Looked at from this perspective it is clear that there is a geography to urban
theory, and one which needs addressing.
This is not a new observation. In 1990, Anthony King wrote that:
The question is whether the real development of London or Manchester can be understood without reference to India,
Africa, and Latin America any more than can the development of Kingston (Jamaica) or Bombay be understood
without the former. Nevertheless, the real division of scholarship, as well as the ideological underpinnings that help to
keep them alive, ensure that histories of ‘First’, ‘Second’ and ‘Third’-World cities are still kept tidily apart (King, 1990:
78).
In his view, and mine, urban studies is deeply divided against itself. It is my contention that this diminishes
the vitality (and certainly narrows the purchase) of urban theory and also, perhaps more importantly, has
certain consequences in the field of urban policy which we ought to be concerned about. Anthony King’s
work (1990; 1995), and a rising interest in both globalization and post-colonialism has meant a partial
redressing of this divide, especially within historical writing and a more culturally-inflected urban studies
(see especially Rabinow, 1989; Jacobs, 1996; Ross, 1996; Driver and Gilbert, 1998).
More hopefully, in the decade or so since King made this observation, urban studies has seen the
consolidation of a significant interest in ‘world cities’ and ‘global cities’ which seeks to understand the
position and functioning of cities within the world- economy. The situation, then, may appear more
propitious than ever for an integration of urban studies across these long-standing divisions of West and
third world. An analytical focus on the transnational global economy could ensure that taken-for-granted
categorizations of cities (western, third-world, African, Asian, socialist etc.) will no longer be of any
relevance. Indeed, this is a claim made by the key advocates of these approaches (Sassen, 2001; Taylor,
2001). The focus of urban theory could arguably shift to understanding the diversity of urban experiences
and cities within the world economy. Could this be the basis for a more ‘cosmopolitan’ account of cities,
rather than one that is divided, resting on partial and limited areas of the globe, and quite divergent sets of
concerns or subject matter?
The article addresses this question by reviewing, in turn, world cities and global cities approaches, the
developmentalist approaches which currently frame most writing on cities in poorer countries, and
emerging transnational and ‘ordinary’ city approaches. The argument is that although there is much scope
in these approaches for broadening our understanding of cities and their futures, there is still considerable
work to be done to produce a cosmopolitan, postcolonial urban studies. Moreover, the stakes are
considerably higher than analytical correctness or theoretical insight. The dearth of alternative
vocabularies and approaches currently severely limits imaginations of possible futures for cities. The
particular form of this limitation, makes it particularly hard to mobilize creative ways to address the
situation of poor and marginalized people in cities around the world.
3 One recent example of this is to be found in Marcuse and van Kempen (2000). Despite specifically inviting people to write in the
volume about cities outside of North America/western Europe, the introductory theoretical material makes no attempt to consider
whether literature on these other cities might suggest alternative approaches. The category of ‘third-world city’ is used without
reflection — despite decades of suggestions from people who work on these places that it is an inaccurate category — and even the
contributions within the volume from these parts of the world are simply relegated to a position of difference. The discussion of the
demise of the welfare state, for example, makes no attempt to consider the relationship between US/European experiences and the
dramatic and widely documented destruction of state capacities in the name of structural adjustment policies.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
534 Jennifer Robinson Global and world cities
Three key conclusions of the initial rounds of world cities research can be summarized as:
● World cities articulate regional, national and international economies into a global economy. They
serve as the organizing nodes of a global economic system.
● World cities can be arranged hierarchically, roughly in accord with the economic power they
command — competition between world cities and the impact of external shocks shape the
fortunes of world cities and their position in the hierarchy. Cities can rise and fall through the
hierarchy, and their position is determined by the relative balance of global, national and regional
influence.
● Many populations are excluded from the space of global capitalism, and thus from the field of
world cities: they are ‘economically irrelevant’ (Knox, 1995: 41).
In his account of cities across the world, King provocatively noted that ‘all cities today are ‘world
cities’’ (1990a: 82). Unfortunately, research and writing within the rubric of the world cities
approach, or hypothesis, has generally not chosen to build on this observation. Rather, in
considering the dynamics of the world economy in relation to cities, a structural analysis of a
small range of economic processes with a certain ‘global’ reach has tended to crowd out an
attentiveness within urban studies to the place and effect of individual cities (King, 1995) and the
diversity of wider connections which shape them (Allen et al., 1999). Although status within the
world city hierarchy has traditionally been based on a range of criteria, including national
standing, location of state and interstate agencies and cultural functions, the primary
determination of status in this framework is economic — as Friedmann (1986: 317) notes: ‘The
economic variable is likely to be decisive for all attempts at explanation’. This has become more,
not less, apparent in the world cities literature, especially as the approach has been closely tied to
world-systems theory, and as more recent research has focused on identifying the transnational
business connections which define the top rank of world cities, labelled ‘global cities’
(Beaverstock et al., 1999; Sassen, 2001).
In world-systems theory more generally, countries across the world are seen to occupy a place
within the hierarchy of the world-economy, and possibly make their way up through the categories
(core, periphery, semi-periphery) embedded in the world- economy approach. Following this, the
world cities approach assumes that cities occupy similar placings with similar capacity to progress
up or fall down the ranks. The country categorizations of core, periphery and semi-periphery in
world-systems theory have therefore been transferred to the analysis of cities, and overlain, albeit
with a slightly different geography, on an extant but outdated vocabulary of categorizations (such
as first/third world) within the field of urban studies.
John Friedmann asks, in his review of ‘World city research — 10 years on’, whether the world city
hypothesis ‘is a heuristic, a way of asking questions about cities in general, or a statement about
a class of particular cities — world cities — set apart from other urban agglomerations by
specifiable characteristics?’ (1995: 22). He suggests that it is both; but that the tendency has
been to categorize cities into a hierarchy, in which ‘world cities’ are at the top of the tree of
influence. This ‘league table’ approach has shaped the ways in which cities around the world
have been represented — or not represented at all — within the world cities literature. From the
dizzy heights of the diagrammer, certain significant cities are identified, labelled, processed and
placed in a hierarchy, with very little attentiveness to the diverse experiences of that city, or even
to extant literature about that place. The danger here is that out of date, unsuitable or unreliable
data (Short et al., 1996; although see Beaverstock et al., 2000), and possibly a lack of familiarity
with some of the regions being considered can lead to the production of maps which are simply
inaccurate. These images of the world (of important) cities have been used again and
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 535
again to illustrate the perspective of world cities theorists. Pressing the analysis towards an emphasis on
the more limited range of transnational business connections characteristic of global cities, Peter Taylor
(2000: 14) notes with disapproval the ‘widespread reporting of . . . a preliminary taxonomy’ of world cities.
Revised versions, though, based on a more restricted range of criteria (connectedness to globalizing
western producer services firms) draw remarkably similar conclusions, and maps.
In both the broader and the more narrow economistic approach to identifying world cities, a view
of the world of cities emerges where millions of people and hundreds of cities are dropped off
the map of much research in urban studies, to service one particular and very restricted view of
significance or (ir)relevance to certain sections of the global economy. Perhaps more
importantly, this methodology reveals an analytical tension between assessing the
characteristics and potential of cities on the basis of the processes which matter as viewed from
within their diverse dynamic social and economic worlds (which, of course, always stretch way
beyond any physical edge to the city), or on the basis of criteria determined by the external
theoretical construct of the world or global economy (see also Varsanyi, 2000). This is at the
heart of how a world cities approach can limit imaginations about the futures of cities, which I
will return to below.
World cities research, then, has moved on from the time of Friedmann’s review and, much influenced by
Saskia Sassen’s (1991; 2001) study, The global city, has adopted an empirical focus on transnational
business and finance networks (e.g. Beaverstock et al., 1999; Morshidi, 2000). Nonetheless, although
aiming to emphasize connections and not
attributes (Beaverstock et al., 2000), and in the most recent work to suggest a more global 4
reach for the world city networks of non-command centres (Taylor et al., 2001), a limited range of cities
still end up categorized in boxes or in diagrammatic maps, and assigned a place in relation to a priori
analytical hierarchies.
In a prominent contribution to the world cities argument, Saskia Sassen (1991; 1994) has coined the term
‘global cities’ to capture what she suggests is a distinctive feature of the current (1980s on) phase of the
world economy: the global organization and increasingly transnational structure of key elements of the
global economy. Her key point is that the spatially dispersed global economy requires locally-based and
integrated organization, and this, she suggests, takes place in global cities. Although many transnational
companies no longer keep their headquarters in central areas of these major cities, the specialized firms
which they rely on to produce the capabilities and innovations necessary for command and control of their
global operations have remained or chosen to establish themselves there. Moreover, it is no longer the
large transnational corporations which are the centre of these functions, but small parts of a few major
cities, she suggests, which play host to and enable the effective functioning through proximity of a
growing number of new producer and business services firms (Sassen, 2001). A similar argument
concerning the benefits of co-location for finance and investment firms, suggests that these cutting-edge
activities are produced in a few major cities. Co-location benefits both these sets of firms as this facilitates
face-to-face interaction and the emergence of trust with potential partners, which is crucial in terms of
enabling innovation and coping with the risk, complexity and speculative character of many of these
activities (Sassen, 1994: 84).
While there have been many criticisms of the empirical basis for claims that ‘global cities’ are significantly
different from other major centres (Abu-Lughod, 1995; Short et
4 In this working paper, the very lowest level of connectivity to a system of transnational firms is identified as characterizing Cairo
and Casablanca, Lagos and Nairobi, Johannesburg and Cape Town. But the power relations in this hierarchy of cities leave the
authors concluding that ‘from this power perspective Sassen’s notion of global cities transcending the North-South divide seems a
trifle sanguine; globalisation begins to look very ‘western’ as soon as we look at direct expressions of power’ (Taylor et al., 2001: 7).
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
536 Jennifer Robinson
al., 1996; Storper, 1997; Smith, 2001), the global city approach deploys a strong analytical emphasis on
process. The category of global city which is identified through this analysis, though, is founded upon a
minor set of economic activities based in only a small part of these cities. They may constitute the more
dynamic sectors of these cities’ economies, but Sassen’s evidence of declining location quotients for
these activities in the 1990s (e.g. 2001: 134–5) suggests that the concentrated growth spurt in this sector
may well be over. And to put these sectors in perspective, in London, for example, where transnational
finance and business services are still most dynamic and highly concentrated, the London Development
Agency suggests that ‘about 70% of employment (in London) is in firms whose main market is national
rather than international’ (LDA, 2000: 18).
The discursive effectiveness of the global city hypothesis depends on the pithy
in terms of the global economy. Mirroring the world city emphasis on a limited range of economic activities
with a certain global reach, as well as its categorizing imperative, the global city approach has a similar
effect, dropping most cities in the world from its vision. If the ‘global city’ were labelled as just another
example of an ‘industrial’ district (perhaps it should rather be called: new industrial districts of
transnational management and control), it might not have attracted the attention it did. But on the positive
side, some of the consequences for cities in poorer parts of the world might have been avoided.
‘Filling in the voids’:6 off the world cities map
According to Sassen, functions of command and control of the global economy also take place in some
formerly peripheral cities, which coordinate global investments, as well as financial and business services
regionally. In her view, this signifies the emergence of a new geography to the periphery — a select group
of cities, some in poorer countries, are now deemed to have ‘global city functions’ although they fall short
of being first-order global cities. She mentions Toronto, Sao Paulo, Mexico City, Miami and Sydney. This
signals something of the ‘end of the third world’ (Harris, 1986) as a category in urban studies.
Nonetheless, Sassen acknowledges that her approach ‘cannot account for the cases of many cities that
may not have experienced any of these developments’ (1994: 7).
Despite this, Sassen joins others in consigning substantial areas of the globe to structural irrelevance:
‘significant parts of Africa and Latin America became unhinged from their hitherto strong ties with world
markets in commodities and raw materials’ (ibid.: 27); and: ‘Alongside these new global and regional
hierarchies of cities is a vast territory that has become increasingly peripheral, increasingly excluded from
the major economic processes that fuel economic growth in the new global economy’ (ibid.: 4). Knox goes
even further to suggest that ‘the mega cities of the periphery will fare no better than the catatonic agrarian
societies that have fuelled their (demographic) growth, and in which both will lapse decisively and
irretrievably into a ‘slow’ economic time zone’ (1995: 15).
There are obviously important ways in which the changing geography of the international economy has
impacted on cities in poorer countries. As Sassen (1994: 83)
5 There are many problems associated with assigning ‘power’ to the category of global city, when the capacities to control
and command which are being identified are located in certain actors and institutions within a small part of the city’s
economy. ‘Cities’ as collective actors, may in fact be rendered relatively powerless in these contexts. Moreover, as John
Allen (1999) astutely points out, it is unclear where power is produced: in the sites Sassen identifies (the city
neighbourhoods) or in the network interactions and flows. Taylor et al. (2001) are beginning to explore the idea of
networked power. But the sloppy thinking that elides categories of cities with economic agents in relation to power
continues to have purchase and, as I will argue below, important effects.
6 From Beaverstock et al. (1999: 457).
identification of the ‘global city’ — a category of cities which are claimed to be powerful 5
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 537
suggests, the place of the ‘developing’ countries as sites of investment for western banks has declined
precipitously since the 1970s oil surpluses were recycled through poor countries; Latin America has been
replaced by South East Asia as the top destination for investment in manufacturing by ‘highly developed’
countries; and many poor countries are now net exporters of capital (ibid.: 63). Nonetheless, within this
approach, the international financial centres of many countries perform important ‘gateway functions’ for
the flow of finance and global business services (ibid.: 173). I certainly appreciate that the focus of global
and more recent world cities work is on a limited set of economic activities, which are assuming an
increasingly transnational form, and in which relatively few cities can hope to participate. But it is the leap
from this very restricted and clearly defined economic analysis, to claims regarding the success and
power of these few cities, their overall categorization on this restricted basis, and the implied broader
structural irrelevance of all other cities, which is of concern. These theoretical claims and categorizing
moves are both inaccurate and harmful to the fortunes of cities defined ‘off the map’.
The ‘end of the third world’ is perhaps an accurate assessment of changes over the last three to four
decades in places like Hong Kong, Singapore, Taiwan, South Korea and even Malaysia, and the
appearance of these city-states or major urban centres in rosters of first- and second-order global cities
reflects this. But in parts of the world where global cities have not been identified — the ‘voids’ of world
and global city approaches — the experience of many countries and cities has been much more uneven
than the analyses I have cited suggest. For many, the 1980s and 1990s have been long decades of little
growth and growing inequality. It is, however, inaccurate to caricature even the poorest regions as
excluded from the global economy or doomed to occupy a slow zone of the world economy. Africa,
frequently written off in these large global analyses, has had a very uneven growth record. As the African
Development Report (2000: 1) notes:
While the continent has, in overall terms, lagged behind other regions, a few countries have produced remarkable
economic results, even by world standards … In an encouraging development, as many as 12 countries are
estimated to have recorded real GDP growth rates above 5% while close to 30 countries had positive real GDP per
capita growth.
It is hard to disagree that some countries and cities have lost many of the trading and investment links
that characterized an earlier era of global economic relations. A country like Zambia, for example, now
one of the most heavily indebted nations in the world, and certainly one of the poorest, has seen the value
of its primary export, copper, plummet on the world market since the 1970s. Its position within an older
international division of labour is no longer economically viable, and it has yet to find a successful path for
future economic growth (Young, 1988; Bonnick, 1997). En route it has suffered the consequences of one
of the World Bank/IMF’s most ruthless Structural Adjustment Programmes (Young, 1988; Clark, 1989).
However, Zambia is also one of the most urbanized countries on the African continent, and its capital city,
Lusaka, is a testimony to the modernist dreams of both the former colonial powers and the
post-independence government (Hansen, 1997). Today, with over 70% of the population in Lusaka
dependent on earnings from the informal sector (government bureaucrats are known to earn less than
some street traders: Moser and Holland, 1997), the once bright economic and social future of this city
must feel itself like a dream — albeit one which was for a time very real to many people (Ferguson, 1999).
Lusaka is certainly not a player in the ‘major economic processes that fuel economic growth in the new
global economy’ (Sassen, 1994: 198). But copper is still exported, as are agricultural goods, and despite
the huge lack of foreign currency (and sometimes because of it) all sorts of links and connections to the
global economy persist. From the World Bank, to aid agencies, international political organizations, and
trade in second- hand clothing and other goods and services, Lusaka is still constituted and reproduced
through its relations with other parts of the country, other cities, and other parts of the
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
538 Jennifer Robinson
region and globe (for example, Hansen, 1994; 1997). The city continues to perform its functions of
national and regional centrality in relation to political and financial services, and operates as a significant
market (and occasionally production site) for goods and services from across the country and the world.
It is one thing, though, to agree that global links are changing, some are being cut, and that power
relations, inequalities and poverty shape the quality of those links (see, for example, Halfani, 1996). It is
quite another to suggest that poor cities and countries are irrelevant to the global economy. When looked
at from the point of view of these places which are allegedly ‘off the map’, the global economy is of
enormous significance in shaping the futures and fortunes of cities around the world. For many poor,
‘structurally irrelevant’ cities, the significance of flows of ideas, practices and resources beyond and into
the city concerned from around the world stands in stark contrast to these claims of irrelevance; as
Shatkin (1998: 381) writes about Phnom Penh: ‘In order to arrive at a proper understanding of the
process of urbanisation in LDCs, it is necessary to examine the ways in which countries interface with the
global economy, as well as the social, cultural and historical legacies that each country carries into the era
of globalisation’. These historical legacies, it is clear from his account, are themselves products of earlier
‘global’ encounters, still very much alive in shaping the global significance of that place in the present.
And to pursue a more polemical line, mineral resources crucial to the global economy are drawn from
some of the poorest countries of the world (as mobile phones depend on a mineral found only in
Zaire/DRC), where financiers and transnational firms negotiate with warlords, corrupt governments and
local armies to keep profits, production and exports flowing (Mbembe, 2001). Widening the compass of
analysis might help to encourage a more critical edge to the global and world cities literature. Moreover, it
is precisely through avoiding ‘risky’ investments (and pursuing vastly exploitative and violent forms of
extraction instead) in the poorest countries and cities in the world that the western financial ‘mode of
production’ is able to aim to secure the stable shareholder returns which maintain post-Fordist finance
based economies (Boyer, 2000). To the extent that they are absent from this aspect of the global
economy, these places may well be central to sustaining it.
On a more positive note, viewed from off the (world cities) map, in its initial versions the world city
hypothesis does suggest a range of criteria by which to assess the role and functions of different cities —
whether they are centres of decision-making and authority in the registers of economic, cultural and
political information (Friedmann and Goetz, 1982; Friedmann, 1986; see, for example, Simon, 1995; Hill
and Kim, 2000; Kelly, 2000; Tyner, 2000; Olds and Yeung, 2002). This means that the distinctive role of
quite a wide variety of cities can be brought into view using this approach. Similarly, the spatial reach of a
city’s influence can vary, and there is scope for thinking about cities whose primary influences are more to
do with their hinterland and nation, than with the global economy. So many more cities might come into
view as significant provincial centres, political or symbolic centres, or perhaps as important transport and
production hubs in national and regional economies. Guarding against economic reductionism and
moving beyond the limitations of the global scale of transnational activities would ensure that the range of
cities of concern to world cities theorists is less exclusive (Varsanyi, 2000).
But there is still King’s claim that ‘all cities are world cities’, which we need to consider. And the fact that
the world cities literature, even in its most nuanced form, persists in defining some cities out of the game,
as ‘excluded from global capitalism’ and therefore as irrelevant to their theoretical reflections. Writers on
cities in Africa, for
example, asked to consider world cities in their region, conclude dismally that there are 7
no world cities on the continent — although they point to Cairo and Johannesburg as potentials (Rakodi,
1997). Scholars of other peripheral places, such as Latin America,
7 And Beaverstock et al. (1999: 455) note in their roster of world cities that ‘Africa has its first city in our list, Johannesburg, but there
are still no world cities found in South Asia or the Middle East’.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 539
wonder about the usefulness of these categories in ‘analysing what is occurring’ (Gilbert, 1998: 174), and
they have little relevance to places in South Asia or in the Middle East/ North Africa. As Stanley (2001: 8)
writes, ‘cities in this region are not on the world map’.
If the category of world city is not applicable to a wide range of cities (Simon, 1995), are there other ways
in which the world city hypothesis might be mobilized in these ‘irrelevant’ cities? A stronger focus on
process than categories could lead one to think about how ‘global’ economic processes affect all cities —
as Marcuse and van Kempen frame it, this leads to a focus on ‘globalizing cities’, since ‘globalisation . . .
is a process that affects all cities in the world, if to varying degrees and varying ways, not only those at
the top of the global hierarchy’ (2000: xvii). This formulation still leaves the enthusiasm about hierarchies
and categories in place, though, and retains an emphasis on economic activities with a ‘global’ reach, but
at least it identifies a research agenda applicable to a wider range of cities.
And most importantly, perhaps, but seldom mentioned, the particular ‘global economy’ which is being
used as the ground and foundation for identifying both place in hierarchy and relevant social and
economic processes, is only one of many forms of
8
global and transnational economic connection.
well look very different were the map-makers to relocate themselves and review significant transnational
networks in a place like Jakarta, or Kuala Lumpur, where ties to Islamic forms of global economic and
political activity might result in a very different list of powerful cities (Allen, 1999; Firman, 1999; see also
White, 1998 on the ethnocentrism of these approaches). Similarly, the transnational activities of agencies
like the World Bank and the IMF who drive the circulation of knowledge and the disciplining power to
recover old bank and continuing bi-lateral and multi-lateral debt from the poorest countries in the world
(debt, it should be pointed out, which in an earlier phase these agencies recommended to poor countries)
would draw another crucial graph of global financial and economic connections shaping (or devastating)
city life.
Despite its investment in analysis of the world-economy and transnational economic processes — and in
some ways because of it — the world cities approach continues to see cities through the lens of
categories, and to privilege the west as the source of economic dynamism and globalization. In this sense
it persists in the lineage of an approach to urban studies which divided up the field of cities according to
pre-given criteria, such as western, or third world. World city theorists also bring these older categories
into play even as they try to capture the ways in which the world is more complicated than this. Knox
writes, for example, that ‘just as we can see the world city-ness of regional metropoli, so we can see the
Third-World-ness of world cities’ (1995: 15). The category of world city is added in to complicate the
pre-existing categorization of cities (and vice versa), but they are still taken to be meaningful descriptors
of the world of cities. Or cities beyond the world city radar are simply not mentioned. For these diverse
cities off the map, alternative analytical approaches beckon.
Developmentalism and third-world cities
Scholars of so-called ‘structurally irrelevant’ cities find it hard to pursue research and policy within the
frame of world cities theory, although some find creative ways to apply it (e.g. Tyner, 2000). As Browder
and Godfrey (1997: 45) point out: ‘Beyond general
8 It is perhaps appropriate here to raise some questions about the data used to classify world cities — data which in Beaverstock et
al. (1999) includes no Japanese banks and only US/UK/Australian and Canadian law firms. These firms may be the largest in the
largest economies in the world, and thus arguably driving the global economy, but this methodology omits potentially significant
dimensions of different economic globalizations and will fail to capture the regional significance of some centres, e.g. in the context
of West Asian and North African cities (see Taylor, 2001).
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
The criteria for global significance might
540 Jennifer Robinson
inferences, the implications of recent world city formation for Third World Urbanisation go largely
uncontemplated’. Instead, an alternative frame of reference for many cities in poor countries has been the
enormous developmentalist (Ferguson, 1990; Escobar, 1995) literature on cities (for recent reviews and
examples, see Pugh, 1995; Burgess et al., 1997; Gugler, 1997; Drakakis-Smith, 2000). A substantial
literature has developed on various aspects of urban development — community participation, housing,
land tenure, service provision, governance capacities, infrastructure, informal sector and so on. All of
these are crucial in so many ways for improving the living environments and livelihoods of people living in
poor cities. But they do not show up on the radar of the wider field of urban studies which claims to be
concerned with the dynamism and centrality of urban life in the contemporary global economy. The one
place where some of these concerns about immense urban poverty do emerge into a wider urban studies
is in the considerations of mega-cities. ‘Big but not powerful’ (Massey et al., 1999: 115; Beaverstock et al.,
1999), mega cities attract other forms of theoretical fascination: with the dark and disturbing side of
urbanization (Lo and Yeung, 1998; Beall, 2000).
In the same way, then, that global and world city approaches ascribe the characteristics of only parts of
cities to the whole city through the process of categorization, mega-city and developmentalist approaches
extend to the entire city the imagination of those parts which are lacking in all sorts of facilities and
services. Where the global city approach generalizes the successful locales of high finance and corporate
city life, the developmentalist approach builds towards a vision of all poor cities as infrastructurally poor
and economically stagnant yet (perversely?) expanding in size. Many other aspects of city life in these
places are obscured, especially dynamic economic activities, popular culture, innovations in urban
governance and the creative production of diverse forms of urbanism — all potentially valuable resources
in the quest for improving urban life (Askew and Logan, 1994; Hansen, 1997; Rakodi, 1997; Simone,
2001). Envisioning city futures on the basis of these partial accounts is certainly limiting. And from the
point of view of urban theory, these developmentalist city experiences do not contribute to expanding the
definition of city-ness: rather they are drawn on to signify its obverse, what cities are not.
This has been a long-standing theme in the criticism of the category of ‘third-world cities’, that their
diverse experiences are pulled through the common lens of third-world- ness, and the resultant distinctive
features are identified and understood in relation to prior western experiences (rehearsed regularly, but
with little apparent effect on the literature: Simon, 1989; King, 1990; McGee, 1995; Drakakis-Smith, 2000).
The split in urban studies identified here has been reinforced by the rise of ‘third world’-ism and the field
of Development Studies, specifically concerned with speeding up the economic growth of less developed
countries (Hewitt, 2000). Within this framework, the poorest cities in the world have been characterized by
their distinctive features as ‘third-world cities’. Although hampered by the idea of ‘urban bias’ in which
cities were seen to be draining the countryside economically, over time a set of strategies have evolved
which are designed to help cities in ‘third-world’ countries address what seem to be their very different
concerns from cities in the West — rapid population growth without economic growth; burgeoning informal
sector activities; a large, poorly housed or homeless population and extensive irregular settlements.
But while cities have been seen as distinctive sites for (transnational) interventions in the form of targeted
development projects mostly at the neighbourhood level, the city as such has been considered broadly
irrelevant to economic growth. Urban economies were seen as the outcome of national and international
decisions and were considered to be the province of authorities at these scales. National development
strategies such as import substitution industrialization had substantial consequences for urban growth, as
manufacturing firms and infrastructural development transformed cities and provided employment
opportunities for the growing population. But the field of ‘urban
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 541
development’ had neglected what Nigel Harris (1992) has called the ‘real urban economy’ for decades.
Economic growth was not considered an important part of urban development, and was much more the
province of national and regional level governments.
Policy-makers interested in promoting development have since come to appreciate the distinctiveness of
individual urban economies, whose successful management and development is now seen as a crucial
determinant of wider economic growth. Starting with a major World Bank (1991) initiative, this approach
saw cities as ‘engines of economic growth’ rather than parasitic drains on the national economy. They
emphasized enabling and partnership strategies for housing and services provision (as opposed to state
or donor provision) and highlighted the importance of infrastructure provision and efficient city-wide
managerial capacity as essential to support economic enterprise.
From the point of view of addressing poverty, too, the stretching of the urban development imagination to
include the city as a whole, rather than targeted projects (although these remain important forms of
development intervention), is increasingly seen as key. As the 2001 Global Report on Human Settlements
notes, addressing inequality is as effective a way of combating poverty as promoting economic growth, if
not more so (UNCHS, 2001: xxxii–iii). But for that both poor and wealthy parts of the city need to be
considered together. From this position (off the world cities map) it is imperative that the imaginations of
the world city analysts and developmentalist urban policy are drawn together. The energy for such a
reintegration of the field of urban studies, though, is much more apparent in the literature concerned with
urban development in poorer cities than it is in the global and world city approaches, which consign the
rest of the world (and its scholarly literatures) to irrelevance!
Recently, then, there has been a theoretical convergence of sorts as advocates of urban economic
development policies have turned to analyses of globalization and urban development (Harris, 1992;
1995; Cohen, 1997). Partly as a result of the World Bank’s earlier policies, the role of city government is
now understood to include the promotion of urban economic development. As Harris summarizes:
hitherto ‘urban development’ has tended to exclude a concern for the underlying urban economy, making it
impossible for city authorities to consider directly measures to enhance urban productivity. The agenda has been
broadened from the immediate issues of maintaining order and providing services, to a concern with the environment
of the poor. It needs now to consider the economy proper, particularly because increased administrative
decentralisation and a more open world economy are likely to make the role of city managers much more important
(however these are identified). This will require considerable inputs of technical assistance, particularly to identify the
city-specific agenda of issues and continuing mechanisms to monitor the changing economy. Hitherto, local
authorities have had little incentive to trouble themselves about the economy within their administration. However,
decentralisation with greater democracy could enforce on local authorities an increasing interest in the sources of the
city’s revenues as well as the citizens’ income (Harris, 1992: 195).
Urban development initiatives at the end of the 1990s have dovetailed with substantial administrative
decentralization in poorer countries to produce a set of policy proposals focusing on promoting urban
economic development at a local level. These initiatives are also reinforced by a growing awareness of
the competitive role of cities across the world in the ‘global’ economy (Wolfensohn, 1999; Stren, 2001).
Drawing on and extending the experiences of local economic development initiatives already prominent in
many western cities, urban development policies in poor countries at the turn of the century have started
to follow the path which Harris was predicting at the beginning of the 1990s. Urban development
initiatives at a city-wide level (called City Development Strategies) are advocated by major international
agencies and increasingly implemented by cities around the world (Campbell, 1999; World Bank, 2000;
UNCHS, 2001).
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
542 Jennifer Robinson
Within the developmentalist framework, cities can be seen as significant new territorializations of the
global economy, following Sassen (2001), Taylor (2000) and Brenner (1998), but arguably for different
reasons than those which they emphasize. In this case it is decentralization, democratization, tighter aid
and policy control by IFIs, as well as new forms of economic liberalization which have contributed to the
growing emphasis of development practice in poorer countries on recognizing the city as a significant site
of developmental planning (Robinson, 2002a). Increasingly, policy- makers suggest that cities which are
well organized and managed can build on their own distinctive combinations of economic activities and
broader assets to act as a competitive platform for attracting and directing economic investment and
encouraging economic growth. This way of thinking about cities and their potential for development has
much in common with other prominent approaches to local economic development which have been
primarily based on the analysis of western cities’ experiences in the context of globalization (Cox and
Mair, 1988; Harvey, 1989; see the section on ‘The policy imperative’ below). However, crucially, this set of
urban development policy approaches have at least proclaimed a sensitivity to the diversity of city
economies, rather than encouraging their subordination to any particular global logic.
In poorer cities, it is precisely the coexistence of local and translocal informal economic
activities, as well as national and transnational formal economic connections, in the context of a
desperate need for basic services, which is challenging policy-makers (see, for example, Parnell
and Pieterse, 1998; Rogerson, 1999; 2000; World Bank, 2000; Robinson, 2002b). Both global
and world city approaches, and the developmentalist literature, have little to contribute on how
to work with this diversity of city economies, rather than only characteristic segments of them.
Neither of them offer us many resources for imagining possible development paths which cut
across and work with the coexistence of ‘global’ formal activities and translocal informal trading,
or help foster links between city-wide or neighbourhood-based firms and the transnational firms
involved with internationally traded commodities which sustain many economies. The challenge
for urban studies, then, is to develop creative ways of thinking about connections across the
diversity and complexity of city economies and city life. This is not simply to more accurately
represent and understand cities, but to contribute to framing policy alternatives which can
encourage support for a diversity of economic activities with a wide range of spatial reaches,
rather than prioritizing only those with a global reach. This would also ensure that urban
interventions could address the inequalities which stretch across and between cities and which
sustain poverty in them (UNCHS, 2001). The following section explores some alternative
approaches which have established some paths beyond the categorizing and hierarchizing
imperatives of global and world cities approaches, and which could potentially stimulate more
creative thinking about city-wide development.
Towards cities without categories Comparative traditions
In one recent attempt to grapple with the divisive geography of urban theory, Dick and
Rimmer (1998) have proposed an assessment of whether ‘third-world’ and ‘western’ 9
cities are becoming more like each other over time (or not). Writing to the title of ‘Beyond the third world
city’, they suggest that there have been periods in which third- world and western cities have converged
(such as the 1880s–1930s when there was an
9 This is a question Michael Cohen (1997) asks too — and answers by suggesting that the developmentalist concerns of southern
cities are broadly applicable to all cities, although he suggests they are ‘similar, if not identical’.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 543
increase in economic and political control exerted by metropolitan powers through colonial rule, trade,
investment and new transport technologies), and periods when they have diverged (such as the
1940s–70s, with the breakdown of colonial political and economic control, the rise of indigenous
administration and the disintegration of infrastructure and prevalence of the informal economy). More
recently, they note that: ‘Convergence between urban forms in metropolitan countries and Southeast Asia
was renewed in the 1980s by increasing trade and investment and the application of telecommunications
and high-speed transport’ (ibid.: 2306).
In their view, Southeast Asian cities have seen first-world forms of investment, such as large-scale private
land development and the proliferation of shopping malls — ‘clearly First World not Third World’ (ibid.:
2316). These developments are dominated by American architectural influences as well as by another set
of American concerns, the ‘perceived deterioration in personal security’ with crime, racism and a sense
that ‘public space has become an area of uncertainty’ (ibid.: 2317). Alongside shopping malls, gated
communities have also appeared on the landscape. They are clear that the processes underpinning these
changes in the urban landscape are somewhat different in Southeast Asia than in the USA. But they
conclude that: ‘The emerging urban forms take after North American patterns to a remarkable degree that
has yet to be recognised, let alone explained . . . Scholars need to challenge prejudices which have
allowed them to partition the world into separate spheres according to their own particular areas of
expertise’ (ibid.: 2319–20). This is certainly a sentiment that I share, and one which goes some way to
addressing my concerns with the dominant world and global city approaches, and the residual category of
cities in need of development. Their strategy, though, retains what I have identified as a rather harmful
categorization of cities and encourages us to assess one (assumed) set of cities in terms of another; even
if the purpose is to show that the categorizations may be more muddled than originally thought. But what
Dick and Rimmer do point to is the diversity of interactions that shape city life. Formal economic networks,
positions of command or dependence in a ‘world-economy’ are only one part of the story about what
makes cities distinctive and what shapes their trajectories (Smith, 2001). They also cite cultural and
architectural trends as well as the importance of tracking a diversity of longer term historical influences on
city life (on which, see Askew and Logan, 1994).
Most writing on cities, though, remains broadly confined to particular national contexts or tracks the
limited world of western economic globalization, both of which draw on literatures restricted to certain
groupings of cities. Furthermore, the limited applicability of different accounts of (western) cities
conventionally remains unstated,
10
even if it is implicit in the content.
work in The urban question (1976) and The city and the grassroots (1983). Both of these theorized on the
basis of material from South America and Europe (and North America in the latter) to develop Castells’
influential accounts of urban politics. This represented a quite different trajectory for theorizing cities and
generated a minor interest in ‘comparative urban politics’ (e.g. Harloe, 1981; Pickvance and Preteceille,
1991), although authors seemed to settle for cross-European or Anglo-American comparisons (this is
repeated in the more recent efforts to think comparatively about regime theory: DiGaetano and
Klemanski, 1993; Stoker and Mossberger, 1994). While most writing did not adopt Castells’ strategy of a
wider transnational frame, there were some comparative pieces on socialist and capitalist cities (for a
recent review, see Szelenyi, 1996).
10 This is much less the case for writing about cities outside the West, where explicit naming of the region or cities covered
highlights the implicit universalist assumptions underpinning the often unremarked localness of much writing on western cities. In
addition, writers on cities outside the West are routinely expected to frame their contributions within the theoretical terms and
concerns of western scholars. Expecting reference to a wider range of cities’ experiences on the part of western writers might be
one strategy for promoting a more cosmopolitan urban theory.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
An important exception was Castells’ innovative
544 Jennifer Robinson
The theoretical possibilities implicit in an earlier tradition of comparative research on cities in Africa, such
as that outlined by Mitchell (1987), have also not been pursued. A much older school of urban studies,
including anthropologists working on the Zambian Copperbelt and influenced by the Chicago School
urban sociologists, focused on what could be learnt in each context (the USA and central Africa) to
advance a general theoretical understanding of urban social life (for recent reviews, see Hansen, 1997;
Ferguson, 1999). As Mitchell (1987: 244) writes: ‘In principle what is being achieved in comparative
analysis is that the manifestation of certain regular relationships among selected theoretically significant
features in the two instances is being demonstrated by showing how the operation of contextual variations
enhances or suppresses the expected pattern’. The ambition was to understand the nature of social life
and interaction in cities, which it was assumed would vary with different structural contexts (racial orders,
rate and nature of economic growth, political power) and also with different situations even within the
same city, or within one person’s life.
It was expected that investigations in the United States and in Africa could inform one another in the task
of understanding social processes in these cities (ibid.: 245). Mitchell does this, for example, by showing
how his analysis of migration to cities in Africa can enhance the understanding of Chinese immigrants’
experiences in US cities (ibid.: 292). Drawing on Philip Mayer’s research on Xhosa migrants to East
London, South Africa, Mitchell extends existing accounts of urban social life, elaborating on the idea of
the city as a ‘network of networks’ (ibid.: 310), in which individuals are located within varying types of
networks of social relations, involving different qualities or intensities of interaction (varying from very
intense and intimate in relation to kinsfolk, for example, to distant and passing in relation to people one
passes on the street — the classic blase ́ urban attitude). Relations between people might be
multidimensional (multiplex) or single-stranded, and counter to the Chicago School’s suggestion that
urban life is characterized by single-stranded, distant and often blase ́ interactions, he suggests that there
are varied kinds of networks in which city dwellers are located, and that depending on the nature of the
social network and the nature of the situation, or place, of interaction, the character of urban social
relations is diverse and changing. These differences are apparent not only between discreet communities
(as with the ‘Red’ or ‘School’ groups amongst Xhosa migrants to East London), but within the life and
daily paths of individuals in the city a variety of different types of social relations are evident.
Dick and Rimmer, Castells and Mitchell’s comparative projects move us towards an alternative way of
dealing with differences amongst cities, within a broader framework of advancing an understanding of
cities and their possible futures. Firstly, they take the time to look beyond the immediate circumstances of
their own research topic: they adopt a cosmopolitan theoretical perspective. Secondly, both examples of
comparative analysis avoid placing the different cities they are considering within a hierarchy, without
losing sight of the distinctiveness of each of the cities or groups of cities. Thirdly, I noted that Dick and
Rimmer direct our attention to the diversity of cultural and economic global, international or transnational
links that shape cities around the world — in their case, from Los Angeles to Jakarta. And, finally, Mitchell
has reminded us that cities are composed of multiple social networks, of varying intensity, associated with
many different kinds of economic and social processes, and with different kinds of locales, or places,
within the city. In a bid to direct our attention to a wider range of social processes and city-spaces than
global, world and developmentalist city approaches bring into view, a number of contemporary writers are
proposing a new approach to ‘ordinary’ cities, which builds on insights such as these. I suggest that these
approaches could also play an important role in enabling urban studies to attend to a wider range of
cities.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 545 Ordinary cities
In place of the global and world city approaches which focus on a small range of economic and political
activities within the restrictive frame of the ‘global’, or developmentalist approaches which bring into view
only poorly serviced parts of poorer cities, a number of writers are offering more generalized accounts of
cities. Michael Storper (1997) has focused on the economic creativity of urban agglomerations in his
description of the ‘reflexive city’. He generalizes the need for ‘proximity’ in economic interactions to
cement relations of trust amongst complex organizations and between individuals and organizations.
Storper sees the city as providing a key context for these reflexivities, so crucial to the ‘untradable’ and
‘tacit’ elements of economic life. However, rather than being limited to a focus on the workings of
single-industry production complexes, or to production chains, or filieres, reflexivity is a generalized
possibility in city life. He suggests, then, that we think of ‘the economies of big cities . . . as sets of
partially overlapping spheres of reflexive economic action . . . [including] their conventional and relational
structures of co-ordination and coherence’ (ibid.: 245). Cities thus remain attractive locations for business
activity across a range of sectors and offer an environment that enables economic production and
innovation. This is to make a case for the broad economic potential of all cities.
Amin and Graham (1997) concur, suggesting that (at least to some extent) cities generally foster
creativity. In western policy circles, they argue, there is a rediscovery of ‘the powers of agglomeration’,
and an excitement about cities as creative centres. Agreeing that many accounts of cities highlight only
certain elements of the city (finance services, information flows) or certain parts of the city — both leading
to a problem of synecdoche — they rather describe (all) cities as ‘the co-presence of multiple spaces,
multiple times and multiple webs of relations, tying local sites, subjects and fragments into globalizing
networks of economic, social and cultural change . . . as a set of spaces where diverse ranges of
relational webs coalesce, interconnect and fragment’ (ibid.: 417– 8). Within this spatialized imaginary of
cities as sites of overlapping networks of relations, in which people, resources and ideas are brought
together in a wide variety of different combinations, within complex geographies of internal differentiation
and dis/ ordering, the futures of cities are both uncertain, to be made, and limited by the historical
circumstances of that city (Allen et al., 1999; Pile et al., 1999; Pryke, 1999; on the path dependency of
urban change, see Harloe, 1996). Power relations are, of course, not absent and crucially shape specific
outcomes.
These approaches stress the importance of acknowledging overlapping networks of interaction within the
city — networks which stretch beyond the physical form of the city and place it within a range of
connections to other places in the world. The range of potential international or transnational connections
is substantial: cultural, political, urban design, urban planning, informal trading, religious influences,
financial, institutional, intergovernmental and so on (Allen, 1999; Smith, 2001). To the extent that it is a
form of economic reductionism (and reductionism to only a small segment of economic activity) which
sustains the regulating fiction of the global city, this spatialized account of the multiple webs of social
relations which produce ordinary cities could help to displace some of the hierarchizing and excluding
effects of this approach.
A diverse range of links with places around the world are a persistent feature of cities. They can work for
or against cities everywhere (Harris, 1995) and are constantly being negotiated and renegotiated. To aim
to be a ‘global city’ in the formulaic sense may well be the ruin of most cities. Policy-makers need to be
offered alternative ways of imagining cities, their differences and their possible futures — neither seeking
a global status nor simply reducing the problem of improving city life to the promotion of ‘development’. In
developmentalist perspectives cities in poor countries are often seen as non-cities, as lacking in city-ness,
as objects of (western) intervention. Ordinary cities, on the other hand
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
546 Jennifer Robinson
(and that means all cities), are understood to be diverse, creative, modern and distinctive, with the
possibility to imagine (within the not inconsiderable constraints of contestations and uneven power
relations) their own futures and distinctive forms of city-ness.
Categorizing cities and carving up the realm of urban studies has had substantial effects on how cities
around the world are understood and has played a role in limiting the scope of imagination about possible
futures for cities. This is as true for cities declared ‘global’ as for those which have fallen off the map of
urban studies. The global cities hypothesis has described cities like New York and London as ‘dual cities’,
with the global functions drawing in not only a highly professional and well-paid skilled labour force, but
also relying on an unskilled, very poorly-paid and often immigrant workforce to service the global
companies (Sassen, 1991; Allen and Henry, 1995). These two extremes by no means capture the range
of employment opportunities or social circumstances in these cities (Fainstein et al., 1992). It is possible
that these cities, allegedly at the top of the global hierarchy, could also benefit from being imagined as
‘ordinary’. The multiplicity of economic, social and cultural networks which make up these cities could
then be drawn on to imagine possible paths to improving living conditions and enhancing economic
growth across the whole city.
The main concern of this article has been with the implications of this divided condition of urban studies
for cities which are hidden from view by these approaches, or intellectually ghettoized in empiricism and
development policy. A more cosmopolitan urban theory might be more accurate or helpful in
understanding the world; it might also be more resourceful and creative in its output. But interrogating
these categorizations of cities and theoretical divisions within urban studies matters primarily, I think,
because they limit our potential to contribute to envisioning possible city futures. And given the gloomy
prognoses for growth in poor cities within the context of the contemporary global economy (e.g. Storper,
1995), creative thinking is certainly needed! As Amin and Thrift commented some time ago: ‘Somewhat
bleakly, then, we are forced to conclude that the majority of localities may need to abandon the illusion of
the possibility of self-sustaining growth and accept the constraints laid down by the process of
increasingly globally integrated industrial development and growth’ (1992: 585).
From the viewpoint of global and world cities approaches, poor localities, and many cities which do not
qualify for global or world city status, are caught within a very limited set of views of urban development:
between finding a way to fit into globalization, emulating the apparent successes of a small range of
cities; and embarking on developmentalist initiatives to redress poverty, maintain infrastructure and
ensure basic service delivery. Neither the costly imperative to go global, nor developmentalist
interventions which build towards a certain vision of city-ness and which focus attention on the failures of
cities, are very rich resources for city planners and managers who turn to scholars for analytical insight
and assessment of experiences elsewhere. It is my opinion that urban studies needs to decolonize its
imagination about city-ness, and about the possibilities for and limits to what cities can become, if it is to
sustain its relevance to the key urban challenges of the twenty-first century. My suggestion is that
‘ordinary-city’ approaches offer a potentially more fertile ground for meeting these challenges.
The policy imperative: the political case for ordinary cities
If cities are not to remain inconsequential, marginalized and impoverished, or to trade economic growth
for expansion in population, the hierarchies and categories of extant urban theory implicitly encourage
them to aim for the top! Global city as a concept becomes a regulating fiction. It offers an authorized
image of city success (so people can buy into it) which also establishes an end point of development for
ambitious cities. There are demands, from Istanbul (Robins and Askoy, 1996) to Mumbai (Harris, 1995),
to be global. As Douglass (1998: 111) writes, ‘world cities are the new shibboleth of global
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 547
achievement for governments in Pacific Asia’ (see also Douglass, 2000; Olds and Yeung, 2002). But, as a
number of authors have noted, calculated attempts at world or global city formation can have devastating
consequences for most people in the city, especially the poorest, in terms of service provision, equality of
access and redistribution (Berner and Korff, 1995; Robins and Askoy, 1996; Douglass, 1998; Firman,
1999). Global and world city approaches encourage an emphasis on promoting economic relations with a
global reach, and prioritizing certain prominent sectors of the global economy for development and
investment. Alternatively, the policy advice is for cities to assume and work towards achieving their
allocated ‘place’ within the hierarchy of world cities (Taylor, 2001).
Most cities in poorer countries would find it hard to reasonably aspire to offering a home for the global
economy’s command and control functions which Sassen identifies as concentrated in certain global
cities. Although, as Tyner (2000) argues, different aspects of the global economy require coordination and
organizing, and some of these activities are concentrated in cities which are not usually labelled as global.
Manila, for example, has a concentration of agencies and institutions which facilitate the movement of
low-paid migrant labour to wealthier countries. More feasible for many poorer cities is to focus on some of
the other ‘global functions’ Sassen associates with global cities. These include promoting attractive
‘global’ tourist environments, even though these have nothing of the locational dynamics of command and
control global city functions. Disconnected from the concentration of arts and culture associated with
employment of highly skilled professionals in global cities, the impulse to become global in purely tourist
terms can place a city at the opposite end of power relations in the global economy, while substantially
undermining provision of basic services to local people (Robins and Askoy, 1996, discuss this in relation
to Istanbul). In addition, Export Processing Zones may be ‘global’ in the sense that they are ‘transnational
spaces within a national territory’ (Sassen, 1994: 1), but they too involve placing the city concerned in a
relatively powerless position within the global economy, which is unlikely to be the city’s best option for
future growth and development (Kelly, 2000). These are not places from where the global economy is
controlled: they are at quite the other end of the command and control continuum of global city functions.
More than that, the reasons for co-location would not involve being able to conduct face-to-face meetings
to foster trust and cooperation in an innovative environment. Rather, they are to ensure participation in the
relaxation of labour and environmental laws which are on offer in that prescribed area of the city. Cities
and national governments often have to pay a high price to attract these kinds of activities to their
territory. Valorizing ‘global’ economic activities as a path to city success — often the conclusion of a policy
reversioning of world cities theory — can have adverse consequences for local economies.
This is a familiar story, but one which scholars are more likely to blame on others — capitalists, elite
urban managers — than on their own analyses, which are seldom the object of such reflection (King,
1995). It is when attention slips from economic process to a sloppy use of categorization that I think the
most damaging effects of the world and global city hypotheses emerge. Categorizing a group of cities as
‘global’ on the basis of these small concentrated areas of transnational management and coordination
activity within them is metonymic in that it has associated entire cities with the success and power of a
small area within them (Amin and Graham, 1997, and as Sassen, 2001, acknowledges). In the process a
valid line of analysis has reproduced a very familiar hierarchization of cities, setting certain cities at the
top of the hierarchy to become the aspiration of city managers around the world.
This has happened just as a burgeoning postcolonial literature became available to critique earlier
categorizations of cities into western and third world (Douglass, 1998), a categorization which had
emphasized difference and deviation from the norm as bases for analysis and which had established
certain (western) cities as the standard towards which all cities should aspire. Instead of pursuing the
postcolonial critique, urban studies has
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
548 Jennifer Robinson
replicated this earlier division by accepting the categories of world/global city as
analytically robust and popularizing them in intellectual and policy circles. Global cities
have become the aspiration of many cities around the world; sprawling and poor megacities the dangerous abyss into which they might fall should they lack the redeeming
(civilizing) qualities of city-ness found elsewhere. This may not have been the intention
11
of urban theorists,
contention that urban theory should be encouraged to search for alternative formulations of city-ness
which don’t rest upon these categories and which draw their inspiration from a much wider range of urban
contexts.
A question which writers about cities in peripheral areas pose, looking at this theory from off the map, is
how to distinguish cities they know from those which can be identified as ‘world’ cities. This leads quite
quickly to asking how cities get to be world cities, as Alan Gilbert (1998: 178) puts it: ‘So what transforms
an ordinary city into a world city?’ But as Mike Douglass (1998; 2000) writes, and Olds and Yeung (2002)
concur, there is little explanation in this literature for ‘world city formation’ — or for how cities become
world cities. Douglass (1998) reminds us that this is a highly contested process with profound
consequences for the built environment of cities and for the wellbeing of citizens.
The emphasis of the world cities approach, then, has been on understanding the ‘structural’ positions of
cities — the ways in which actors and institutions as active agents in cities make the world city-ness of
cities have not been very well explored (see Machimura, 1998; Douglass, 2000; Varsanyi, 2000). It is
likely that these processes of world city formation are of most relevance to those cities defined off the
map of world cities, but eager to make their way onto it. And these are usually not very progressive or
helpful processes. They have been much discussed elsewhere in urban studies, including
place-marketing, tourist promotion, subsidies to attract productive enterprises, costly remaking of the
urban environment, all relying on often destructive forms of competition between cities and the
emergence of copy-cat forms of urban entrepreneurialism (Logan and Molotch, 1987; Harvey, 1989;
Berner and Korff, 1995; Hall and Hubbard, 1998; Beauregard and Pierre, 2000; Jessop and Sum, 2000).
Critically evaluating these world- city-making processes and incorporating them into their explanatory
frameworks and empirical research (they are notably absent from the key studies within the field: Sassen,
1994; 2001 and the GAWC ‘global observatory’ project at Loughborough) could help to sustain the critical
edge of the world cities approach, and also ensure that it remains a ‘heuristic’ rather than categorizing
device (Friedmann, 1995). A greater emphasis on process rather than assigning cities to a category
would certainly enable the world cities approach to be more applicable to cities off its maps — but it might
also lead us to dismiss the activity of categorizing cities altogether and vastly widen the relevant range of
processes, both geographically and functionally (Smith and Timberlake, 1995).
The political need for a new generation of urban theoretical initiatives is apparent. How can the
overlapping and multiple networks highlighted in the ordinary city approaches be drawn on to inspire
alternative models of development, which see the connections, rather than conflict, between informal and
formal economies? Approaches which explore links between the diversity of economic activities in any
(ordinary) city (Jacobs, 1961: 180–1), and which emphasize the general creative potential of cities, are
crucial, rather than those which encourage policy-makers to support one (global) sector to the detriment
of others. How can urban managers be convinced that the spatial reach of an activity is no guarantee of
its value to a city (whether this be local or global activities)? Here again, creative work is being done in
poorer cities, outside the purview of dominant
11 As Saskia Sassen commented at a recent conference (Urban Futures, Johannesburg, 2000), she is often asked to advise city
authorities on their development plans, and always advises them to look to the specific advantages of that city, rather than be driven
by an externally derived set of ambitions.
but ideas have a habit of circulating beyond our control. It is my
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 549
approaches. For example, Benjamin (2000) reports on economic clusters in Bangalore which embrace a
range of diverse but interconnected activities. Simone (2001) suggests that ‘ephemeral’ or temporary
public spaces enable actors from all sorts of sectors, involved in all sorts of different enterprises to meet
together for a while and explore the potential interactions across a range of resources and contacts often
kept apart in city spaces. Such studies and examples extend the classic uni-sectoral western industrial
cluster model, and extend ideas about how proximity in cities can support creativity. This should offer
some significant food for thought for both academics and policy-makers. But so long as the discursive
field of urban development remains both divided and hegemonized by global and world cities and
developmentalist approaches, these insights will unfortunately probably fail to impress policy-makers and
academics alike.
Conclusion
The academic field of urban studies ought to be able to contribute its resources more effectively to the
creative imagining of possible city futures around the world. One step in this direction would be to break
free of the categorizing imperative, and to reconsider approaches which are at best irrelevant and at worst
harmful to poor cities around the world. I have suggested that in place of world, global, mega-, Asian,
African, former Socialist, European, third-world etc. cities, urban studies embark on a cosmopolitan
project of understanding ordinary cities (Jacobs, 1961; Amin and Graham, 1997).
A second step must be to decolonize the field of urban studies. Theoretical reflections should at least be
extremely clear about their limited purchase and, even better, extend the geographical range of empirical
resources and scholarly insight for theorizing beyond the West and western-dominated forms of
globalization. This has been initiated in a restricted form, through the transnational emphasis of global
and world cities approaches, and the growing interest in globalization within a developmentalist frame.
But a more cosmopolitan empirical basis for understanding what cities are, and how they function, is
essential to the future relevance of the field of urban studies. In an age — as the World Bank and other
international agencies like to remind us — when most people now live in cities, and most of this urban
population is in poor countries, irrelevance is a very real possibility for a field whose wellsprings of
authorized theoretical innovation remain firmly fixated on the West and its successful satellites and
partners.
This is not to insist that every study consider everywhere. But there is considerable scope for the spatial
trajectories of theoretical imaginings to come closer to the spatiality of cities themselves, which are
constituted on the basis of ideas, resources and practices drawn from a variety of places — not infinite,
but diverse — beyond their physical borders. The conditions of incorporation though, are crucial. Firstly,
simply mobilizing evidence of difference and possibly deviation within the frame of dominant theory is not
enough. Such as in world cities’ caricatures of post-socialist economies (Beaverstock et al., 1999), or
various efforts to include ‘developing’ cities alongside examples more familiar to the western literature
(Marcuse and van Kempen, 2000; Marvin and Graham, 2001; Scott, 2001). Consideration needs to be
given to the difference the diversity of cities makes to theory (not simply noting the difference that they
are). How are theoretical approaches changed by considering different cities and different contexts, by
adopting a more cosmopolitan approach? And here, even Marvin and Graham’s (2001) excellent study,
Splintering urbanism, which specifically sets out to cast a broader net across cities normally kept apart in
urban theory, still managed to write their theoretical piece with no reference to places or literatures
beyond the purview of western and global cities analyses. And secondly, as with cities themselves, power
relations and their geographies cannot be avoided. If a cosmopolitan urban theory is to emerge, scholars
in privileged western environments will need to find responsible and ethical ways to engage with, learn
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
550 Jennifer Robinson
from and promote the ideas of intellectuals in less privileged places. This is not a call to western writers to
appropriate other places for continued western intellectual advantage. It is a plea to acknowledge the
intellectual creativity of scholars and urban managers in a wider range of urban contexts. Of course, this
is a project which already has a place within this intellectual field — and the IJURR has played a not
inconsiderable part in this — but it is one which I am suggesting needs renewed vigour if it is to be taken
further, and to actually make a difference to how cities and their futures are thought.
This will involve a critical analysis of the field’s own complicity in propagating certain limited views of
cities, and thereby undermining the potential to creatively imagine a range of alternative urban futures. It
will require more cosmopolitan trajectories for the sources and resources of urban theory. Much
innovative work is already being undertaken by scholars and policy-makers around the world, who have
had to grapple with the multiplicity, diversity and ordinariness of their cities for some time. Ordinary cities
are themselves enabling new kinds of urban imaginaries to emerge — it is time urban studies caught up.
More than that, I would suggest that as a community of scholars we have a responsibility to let cities be
ordinary.
Jennifer Robinson ([email protected]), Faculty of Social Sciences, The Open University,
Walton Hall, Milton Keynes MK7 6AA, UK.
References
Abu-Lughod, J. (1995) Comparing Chicago, New York and Los Angeles: testing some world city hypotheses. In P.
Knox and P. Taylor (eds.), World cities in a world-system, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
African Development Bank (2000) African development report. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Allen, J. (1999) Cities
of power and influence: settled formations. In J. Allen, D. Massey and M.
Pryke (eds.), Unsettling cities, Routledge, London.
—— and N. Henry (1995) Growth at the margins: contract labour in a core region. In C.
Hadjimichaelis and D. Sadler (eds.), Europe at the margins, Wiley, London.
——, D. Massey and M. Pryke (eds.) (1999) Unsettling cities. Routledge, London.
Amin, A. and S. Graham (1997) The ordinary city. Transactions of the Institute of British
Geographers 22, 411–29.
—— and N. Thrift (1992) Neo-Marshallian nodes in global networks. International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research 4, 571–87.
Andrusz, G., M. Harloe and I. Szelenyi (eds.) (1996) Cities after socialism. Blackwell, Oxford. Askew, M. and W.
Logan (1994) Cultural identity and urban change in Southeast Asia:
interpretative essays. Deakin University Press, Victoria.
Beall, J. (2000) Life in the cities. In T. Allen and A. Thomas (eds.), Poverty and development into
the 21st century, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Beauregard, R. and J. Pierre (2000) Disputing the global: a sceptical view of locality-based
international initiatives. Policy and Politics 28.4, 465–78.
Beaverstock, J., P. Taylor and R. Smith (1999) A roster of world cities. Cities 16.6, 444–58. ——, R.G. Smith and P.J.
Taylor (2000) World-city network: a new metageography? Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 90, 123–34.
Benjamin, S. (2000) Governance, economic settings and poverty in Bangalore. Environment and
Urbanisation 12.1, 35–56.
Berner, E. and R. Korff (1995) Globalisation and local resistance: the creation of localities in
Manila and Bangkok. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 19.2, 208–22. Bhabha, H. (1994) The
location of culture. Routledge, London.
Bonnick, G.C. (1997) Zambia country assistance review: turning an economy around. World
Bank, Washington.
Boyer, R. (2000) Is a finance-led growth regime a viable alternative to Fordism? A preliminary
analysis. Economy and Society 29.1, 111–45.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 551
Brenner, N. (1998) Global cities, glocal states: global city formation and state territorial restructuring in contemporary
Europe. Review of International Political Economy 5, 1–37. Browder, J.O. and B.J. Godfrey (1997) Rainforest cities:
urbanisation, development and
globalization of the Brazilian Amazon. Columbia University Press, New York.
Burgess, R., M. Carmona and T. Kolstee (eds.) (1997) The challenge of sustainable cities: neoliberalism and urban strategies in developing countries. Zed Books, London.
Campbell, T. (1999) The changing prospects for cities in development — the case of Vietnam. In World Bank,
Business briefing: world urban economic development, Official briefing for World
Competitive Cities Congress, Washington, DC.
Castells, M. (1976) The urban question. Edward Arnold, London.
—— (1983) The city and the grassroots. Edward Arnold, London.
Chakrabarty, D. (2000) Provincialising Europe. Routledge, London.
Cheah, P. and B. Robbins (eds.) (1998) Cosmopolitics. Thinking and feeling beyond the nation.
University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.
Clark, J. with C. Allison (1989) Zambia. Debt and poverty. Oxfam, Oxford.
Clifford, J. (1997) Routes: travel and translation in the late twentieth century. Harvard University
Press, Cambridge, MA.
Cohen, M.A. (1997) The hypothesis of urban convergence: are cities in the North and South
becoming more alike in an age of globalisation? In M.A. Cohen, B.A. Ruble, J.S. Tulchin and A.M. Garland (eds.),
Preparing for the urban future: global pressures and local forces, Woodrow Wilson Centre Press, Washington, DC.
Cox, K. and A. Mair (1988) Locality and community in the politics of local economic development. Annals of the
Association of American Geographers 78, 307–25.
Dick, H.W. and P.J. Rimmer (1998) Beyond the third world city: the new urban geography of Southeast Asia. Urban
Studies 35.12, 2303–21.
DiGaetano, A. and J. Klemanski (1993) Urban regimes in comparative perspective: the politics of urban development
in Britain. Urban Affairs Quarterly 29.1, 54–83.
Douglass, M. (1998) World city formation in the Asia Pacific Rim: poverty, ‘everyday’ forms of civil society and
environmental management. In M. Douglass and J. Friedmann (eds.), Cities for citizens, John Wiley, Chichester.
—— (2000) The rise and fall of world cities in the changing space-economy of globalisation: comment on Peter J.
Taylor’s ‘World cities and territorial states under conditions of contemporary globalistion’. Political Geography 19,
43–9.
Drakakis-Smith, D. (2000) Third world cities. Routledge, London.
Driver, F. and D. Gilbert (1998) Heart of empire? Landscape, space and performance in imperial
London. Society and Space 16, 1–126.
Escobar, A. (1995) Encountering development: the making and unmaking of the third world.
Princeton University Press, Princeton, NJ.
Fainstein, S., I. Gordon and M. Harloe (eds.) (1992) Divided cities. Blackwell, Oxford. Ferguson, J. (1990) The
anti-politics machine. University of Minnesota Press, Minneapolis.
—— (1999) Expectations of modernity: myths and meanings of urban life on the Zambian
copperbelt. University of California Press, Berkeley.
Firman, T. (1999) From ‘global city’ to ‘city of crisis’: Jakarta Metropolitan Region under
economic turmoil. Habitat International 23.4, 447–66.
Friedmann, J. (1986) The world city hypothesis. Development and Change 17, 69–84.
—— (1995) Where we stand now: a decade of world city research. In P. Knox and P. Taylor (eds.),
World cities in a world system, Cambridge University Press, Cambridge.
—— and W. Goetz (1982) World city formation. An agenda for research and action. International
Journal of Urban and Regional Research 6, 309–44.
Gilbert, A. (1998) World cities and the urban future: the view from Latin America. In F. Lo and Y.
Yeung (eds.), Globalisation and the world of large cities, UN University Press, Tokyo. Gugler, J. (ed.) (1997) Cities in
the developing world: issues, theory and policy. Oxford University
Press, Oxford.
Gupta, A. and J. Ferguson (1999) Culture, power, place: explorations in cultural anthropology.
Duke University Press, London.
Halfani, M. (1996) Marginality and dynamism: prospects for the sub-Saharan African city. In M.A.
Cohen, B.A. Ruble, J.S. Tulchin and A.M. Garland (eds.), Preparing for the urban future: global pressures and local
forces, Woodrow Wilson Centre Press, Washington, DC.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
552 Jennifer Robinson
Hall, T. and P. Hubbard (eds.) (1998) The entrepreneurial city: geographies of politics, regime and representation.
Wiley, Chichester.
Hansen, K. (1994) Dealing with used clothing: salaula and the construction of identity in Zambia’s Third Republic.
Public Culture 6, 503–23.
—— (1997) Keeping house in Lusaka. Columbia University Press, New York.
Harloe, M. (1981) Notes on comparative urban research. In M. Dear and A. Scott (eds.),
Urbanisation and urban planning in capitalist society, Methuen, London.
—— (1996) Cities in the transition. In G. Andrusz, M. Harloe and I. Szelenyi (eds.), Cities after
socialism, Blackwell, Oxford.
Harris, N. (1986) The end of the third world. Penguin, London.
—— (1992) Cities in the 1990s. UCL Press, London.
—— (1995) Bombay in a global economy: structural adjustment and the role of cities. Cities 12.3,
175–84.
Harvey, D. (1989) From managerialism to entrepreneurialism: the transformation of urban
governance in late capitalism. Geografiska Annaler 71B, 3–17.
Hewitt, T. (2000) Half a century of development. In T. Allen and A. Thomas (eds.), Poverty and
development into the 21st Century. Oxford University Press, Oxford.
Hill, R.C and J.W. Kim (2000) Global cities and developmental states: New York, Tokyo and
Seoul. Urban Studies 37.12, 2167–95.
Jacobs, J. (1961) The death and life of great American cities. Penguin, Harmondsworth.
—— (1996) Edge of empire: postcolonialism and the city. Routledge, London.
Jessop, B. and N. Sum (2000) An entrepreneurial city in action: Hong Kong’s emerging strategies
in and for (inter) urban competition. Urban Studies 37.12, 2287–313.
Kelly, P. (1999) Everyday urbanisation: the social dynamics of development in Manila’s extended
metropolitan region. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 23.2, 283–303. —— (2000) Landscapes
of globalization. Human geographies of economic change in the
Philippines. Routledge, London.
King, A. (1990) Urbanism, colonialism and the world-economy. Routledge, London.
—— (1995) Re-presenting world cities: cultural theory/social practice. In P. Knox and P. Taylor
(eds.), World cities in a world-system, Routledge, London.
Knox, P. (1995) World cities in a world-system. In P. Knox and P. Taylor (eds.), World cities in a
world-system, Routledge, London.
Lo, F-C. and Y-M. Yeung (eds.) (1998) Globalisation and the world of large cities. UN University
Press, Tokyo.
Logan, J. and H. Molotch (1987) Urban fortunes: the political economy of place. University of
California Press, Berkeley.
London Development Agency (2000) London development strategy. LDA, London.
Machimura, T. (1998) Symbolic use of globalization in urban politics in Tokyo. International
Journal of Urban and Regional Research 22.2, 183–94.
Marcuse, P. and R. van Kempen (2000) Globalising cities: a new spatial order? Blackwell,
Oxford.
Marvin, S. and S. Graham (2001) Splintering urbanism: networked infrastructures, technological
mobilities and the urban condition. Routledge, London and New York.
Massey, D., J. Allen and S. Pile (eds.) (1999) City worlds. Routledge and the Open University,
London.
Mbembe, A. (2001) On the postcolony. University of California Press, Berkeley.
McGee, T. (1995) Eurocentrism and geography: reflections on Asian urbanisation. In J. Crush
(ed.), Power of development, Routledge, London.
Mitchell, J.C. (1987) Cities, society, and social perception. A Central African perspective.
Clarendon Press, Oxford.
Morshidi, S. (2000) Globalising Kuala Lumpur and the strategic role of the producer services
sector. Urban Studies 37.12, 2217–40.
Moser, C. and J. Holland (1997) Household responses to poverty and vulnerability. Vol 4.
Confronting crisis in Chawama, Lusaka, Zambia. Urban Management Programme, The World
Bank, Washington, DC.
Olds, K. and H. Yeung (2002) From the global city to globalising cities: views from a
developmental city-state in Pacific Asia. Review of International Political Economy (forthcoming).
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
Global and world cities: a view from off the map 553
Parnell, S. and E. Pieterse (1998) Developmental local government. Isandla Working Paper. Pickvance, C. and E.
Preteceille (eds.) (1991) State restructuring and local power: a comparative
perspective. Pinter, London.
Pile, S., C. Brook and C. Mooney (eds.) (1999) Unruly cities? Routledge, London.
Pryke, M. (1999) Open futures. In J. Allen, D. Massey and M. Pryke (eds.), Unsettling cities,
Routledge, London.
Pugh, C. (1995) Urbanisation in developing countries: an overview of the economic and policy
issues in the 1990s. Cities 12.6, 381–98.
Rabinow, P. (1989) French modern. MIT Press, Cambridge, MA.
Rakodi, C. (ed.) (1997) The urban challenge in Africa: growth and management of its large cities.
UN University Press, Tokyo.
Robins, K. and A. Askoy (1996) Istanbul between civilisation and discontent. City 5.6, 6–33. Robinson, J. (2002a) City
futures: new territories for development studies? In J. Robinson (ed.),
Development and displacement, Oxford University Press, Oxford.
—— (2002b) Johannesburg’s futures: between developmentalism and global success. In R.
Tomlinson, R. Beauregard, L. Bremner and X. Mangcu (eds.), Emerging Johannesburg,
Routledge, London.
Rogerson, C. (1999) Local economic development and urban poverty alleviation: the experience of
post-apartheid South Africa. Habitat International 23.4, 511–34.
—— (2000) Local economic development in an era of globalisation: the case of South African
cities. Tijdschrift voor Economische en Sociale Geografie 91.4, 397–411.
Ross, K. (1996) Fast cars, clean bodies: decolonization and the reordering of French culture. MIT
Press, Cambridge, MA.
Sassen, S. (1991) The global city: New York, London, Tokyo. Princeton University Press, Princeton,
NJ.
—— (1994) Cities in a world economy. Pine Forge Press, Thousand Oaks, CA.
—— (2001) The global city: New York, London, Tokyo. Second edition, Princeton University
Press, Princeton, NJ.
Scott, A. (ed.) (2001) Global city-regions: trends, theory, policy. Oxford University Press, Oxford. Shatkin, G. (1998)
‘Fourth world’ cities in the global economy: the case of Phnom Penh.
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 22, 378–93.
Short, J.R., Y. Kim, M. Kuus and H. Wells (1996) The dirty little secret of world cities research:
data problems in comparative analysis. International Journal of Urban and Regional Research
20.4, 697–717.
Simon, D. (1989) Colonial cities, postcolonial Africa and the world economy: a reinterpretation.
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 13, 68–91.
—— (1995) The world city hypothesis: reflections from the periphery. In P. Knox and P. Taylor
(eds.), World cities in a world-system, Routledge, London.
Simone, A. (2001) Straddling the divides: remaking associational life in the informal African city.
International Journal of Urban and Regional Research 25.1, 102–17.
Smith, D. and M. Timberlake (1995) Cities in global matricies: toward mapping the world- system’s city system. In P.
Knox and P. Taylor (eds.), World cities in a world-system,
Routledge, London.
—— (2001) Transnational urbanism. Blackwell, Oxford.
Stanley, B. (2001) ‘Going global’ and wannabe world cities: (re) conceptualising regionalism in the
Middle East. GAWC Research Bulletin 45 (http://www.loughborough.ac.uk/gawc).
Stewart, D. (1999) Changing Cairo: the political economy of urban form. International Journal of
Urban and Regional Research 23.1, 128–46.
Stoker, G. and K. Mossberger (1994) Urban regime theory in comparative perspective.
Environment and Planning C: Government and Policy 12.2, 195–212.
Storper, M. (1995) Territorial development in the global learning economy: the challenge to
developing countries. Review of International Political Economy 2, 394–424.
—— (1997) The regional world. Guilford Press, London and New York.
Stren, R. (2001) Local governance and social diversity in the developing world: new challenges for
globalising city-regions. In A. Scott (ed.), Global city-regions: trends, theory, policy, Oxford
University Press, Oxford.
Szelenyi, I. (1996) Cities under socialism – and after. In G. Andrusz, M. Harloe and I. Szelenyi
(eds.), Cities after socialism, Blackwell, Oxford.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002
554 Jennifer Robinson
Taylor, P. (2000) World cities and territorial states under conditions of contemporary globalisation. Political Geography
19, 5–32.
—— (2001) West Asian/North African cities in the world city network: a global analysis of dependence, integration
and autonomy. GAWC Research Bulletin 58 (http://www.loughbor- ough.ac.uk/gawc).
——, D. Walker, G. Catalano and M. Hoyler (2001) Diversity and power in the world city network. GAWC Research
Bulletin 56 (http://www.loughborough.ac.uk/gawc).
Tyner, J.A. (2000) Global cities and circuits of global labour: the case of Manila, Philippines. Professional Geographer
52, 61–74.
UNCHS (2001) Cities in a globalising world: global report on human settlements 2001. Earthscan (UNCHS), London.
Varsanyi, M. (2000) Global cities from the ground up: a response to Peter Taylor. Political Geography 19, 33–8.
White, J. (1998) Old wine, cracked bottle? Tokyo, Paris and the global city hypothesis. Urban Affairs Review 33.4,
451–77.
Wolfensohn, J. (1999) Foreword from the World Bank. In World Bank, Business briefing: world urban economic
development, Official briefing for World Competitive Cities Congress, World Bank, Washington, DC.
World Bank (1991) Urban policy and economic development: an agenda for the 1990s. A World Bank policy paper.
World Bank, Washington, DC.
—— (2000) Cities in transition. World Bank urban and local government strategy. World Bank, Washington, DC.
Young, R. (1988) Zambia. Adjusting to poverty. The North-South Institute, Ottawa.
ß Joint Editors and Blackwell Publishers Ltd 2002


Get Professional Assignment Help Cheaply

Buy Custom Essay

Are you busy and do not have time to handle your assignment? Are you scared that your paper will not make the grade? Do you have responsibilities that may hinder you from turning in your assignment on time? Are you tired and can barely handle your assignment? Are your grades inconsistent?

Whichever your reason is, it is valid! You can get professional academic help from our service at affordable rates. We have a team of professional academic writers who can handle all your assignments.

Why Choose Our Academic Writing Service?

  • Plagiarism free papers
  • Timely delivery
  • Any deadline
  • Skilled, Experienced Native English Writers
  • Subject-relevant academic writer
  • Adherence to paper instructions
  • Ability to tackle bulk assignments
  • Reasonable prices
  • 24/7 Customer Support
  • Get superb grades consistently

Online Academic Help With Different Subjects

Literature

Students barely have time to read. We got you! Have your literature essay or book review written without having the hassle of reading the book. You can get your literature paper custom-written for you by our literature specialists.

Finance

Do you struggle with finance? No need to torture yourself if finance is not your cup of tea. You can order your finance paper from our academic writing service and get 100% original work from competent finance experts.

Computer science

Computer science is a tough subject. Fortunately, our computer science experts are up to the match. No need to stress and have sleepless nights. Our academic writers will tackle all your computer science assignments and deliver them on time. Let us handle all your python, java, ruby, JavaScript, php , C+ assignments!

Psychology

While psychology may be an interesting subject, you may lack sufficient time to handle your assignments. Don’t despair; by using our academic writing service, you can be assured of perfect grades. Moreover, your grades will be consistent.

Engineering

Engineering is quite a demanding subject. Students face a lot of pressure and barely have enough time to do what they love to do. Our academic writing service got you covered! Our engineering specialists follow the paper instructions and ensure timely delivery of the paper.

Nursing

In the nursing course, you may have difficulties with literature reviews, annotated bibliographies, critical essays, and other assignments. Our nursing assignment writers will offer you professional nursing paper help at low prices.

Sociology

Truth be told, sociology papers can be quite exhausting. Our academic writing service relieves you of fatigue, pressure, and stress. You can relax and have peace of mind as our academic writers handle your sociology assignment.

Business

We take pride in having some of the best business writers in the industry. Our business writers have a lot of experience in the field. They are reliable, and you can be assured of a high-grade paper. They are able to handle business papers of any subject, length, deadline, and difficulty!

Statistics

We boast of having some of the most experienced statistics experts in the industry. Our statistics experts have diverse skills, expertise, and knowledge to handle any kind of assignment. They have access to all kinds of software to get your assignment done.

Law

Writing a law essay may prove to be an insurmountable obstacle, especially when you need to know the peculiarities of the legislative framework. Take advantage of our top-notch law specialists and get superb grades and 100% satisfaction.

What discipline/subjects do you deal in?

We have highlighted some of the most popular subjects we handle above. Those are just a tip of the iceberg. We deal in all academic disciplines since our writers are as diverse. They have been drawn from across all disciplines, and orders are assigned to those writers believed to be the best in the field. In a nutshell, there is no task we cannot handle; all you need to do is place your order with us. As long as your instructions are clear, just trust we shall deliver irrespective of the discipline.

Are your writers competent enough to handle my paper?

Our essay writers are graduates with bachelor's, masters, Ph.D., and doctorate degrees in various subjects. The minimum requirement to be an essay writer with our essay writing service is to have a college degree. All our academic writers have a minimum of two years of academic writing. We have a stringent recruitment process to ensure that we get only the most competent essay writers in the industry. We also ensure that the writers are handsomely compensated for their value. The majority of our writers are native English speakers. As such, the fluency of language and grammar is impeccable.

What if I don’t like the paper?

There is a very low likelihood that you won’t like the paper.

Reasons being:

  • When assigning your order, we match the paper’s discipline with the writer’s field/specialization. Since all our writers are graduates, we match the paper’s subject with the field the writer studied. For instance, if it’s a nursing paper, only a nursing graduate and writer will handle it. Furthermore, all our writers have academic writing experience and top-notch research skills.
  • We have a quality assurance that reviews the paper before it gets to you. As such, we ensure that you get a paper that meets the required standard and will most definitely make the grade.

In the event that you don’t like your paper:

  • The writer will revise the paper up to your pleasing. You have unlimited revisions. You simply need to highlight what specifically you don’t like about the paper, and the writer will make the amendments. The paper will be revised until you are satisfied. Revisions are free of charge
  • We will have a different writer write the paper from scratch.
  • Last resort, if the above does not work, we will refund your money.

Will the professor find out I didn’t write the paper myself?

Not at all. All papers are written from scratch. There is no way your tutor or instructor will realize that you did not write the paper yourself. In fact, we recommend using our assignment help services for consistent results.

What if the paper is plagiarized?

We check all papers for plagiarism before we submit them. We use powerful plagiarism checking software such as SafeAssign, LopesWrite, and Turnitin. We also upload the plagiarism report so that you can review it. We understand that plagiarism is academic suicide. We would not take the risk of submitting plagiarized work and jeopardize your academic journey. Furthermore, we do not sell or use prewritten papers, and each paper is written from scratch.

When will I get my paper?

You determine when you get the paper by setting the deadline when placing the order. All papers are delivered within the deadline. We are well aware that we operate in a time-sensitive industry. As such, we have laid out strategies to ensure that the client receives the paper on time and they never miss the deadline. We understand that papers that are submitted late have some points deducted. We do not want you to miss any points due to late submission. We work on beating deadlines by huge margins in order to ensure that you have ample time to review the paper before you submit it.

Will anyone find out that I used your services?

We have a privacy and confidentiality policy that guides our work. We NEVER share any customer information with third parties. Noone will ever know that you used our assignment help services. It’s only between you and us. We are bound by our policies to protect the customer’s identity and information. All your information, such as your names, phone number, email, order information, and so on, are protected. We have robust security systems that ensure that your data is protected. Hacking our systems is close to impossible, and it has never happened.

How our Assignment Help Service Works

1. Place an order

You fill all the paper instructions in the order form. Make sure you include all the helpful materials so that our academic writers can deliver the perfect paper. It will also help to eliminate unnecessary revisions.

2. Pay for the order

Proceed to pay for the paper so that it can be assigned to one of our expert academic writers. The paper subject is matched with the writer’s area of specialization.

3. Track the progress

You communicate with the writer and know about the progress of the paper. The client can ask the writer for drafts of the paper. The client can upload extra material and include additional instructions from the lecturer. Receive a paper.

4. Download the paper

The paper is sent to your email and uploaded to your personal account. You also get a plagiarism report attached to your paper.

smile and order essay GET A PERFECT SCORE!!! smile and order essay Buy Custom Essay


Place your order
(550 words)

Approximate price: $22

Calculate the price of your order

550 words
We'll send you the first draft for approval by September 11, 2018 at 10:52 AM
Total price:
$26
The price is based on these factors:
Academic level
Number of pages
Urgency
Basic features
  • Free title page and bibliography
  • Unlimited revisions
  • Plagiarism-free guarantee
  • Money-back guarantee
  • 24/7 support
On-demand options
  • Writer’s samples
  • Part-by-part delivery
  • Overnight delivery
  • Copies of used sources
  • Expert Proofreading
Paper format
  • 275 words per page
  • 12 pt Arial/Times New Roman
  • Double line spacing
  • Any citation style (APA, MLA, Chicago/Turabian, Harvard)

Our guarantees

Delivering a high-quality product at a reasonable price is not enough anymore.
That’s why we have developed 5 beneficial guarantees that will make your experience with our service enjoyable, easy, and safe.

Money-back guarantee

You have to be 100% sure of the quality of your product to give a money-back guarantee. This describes us perfectly. Make sure that this guarantee is totally transparent.

Read more

Zero-plagiarism guarantee

Each paper is composed from scratch, according to your instructions. It is then checked by our plagiarism-detection software. There is no gap where plagiarism could squeeze in.

Read more

Free-revision policy

Thanks to our free revisions, there is no way for you to be unsatisfied. We will work on your paper until you are completely happy with the result.

Read more

Privacy policy

Your email is safe, as we store it according to international data protection rules. Your bank details are secure, as we use only reliable payment systems.

Read more

Fair-cooperation guarantee

By sending us your money, you buy the service we provide. Check out our terms and conditions if you prefer business talks to be laid out in official language.

Read more
error: Content is protected !!
Open chat
1
Need assignment help? You can contact our live agent via WhatsApp using +1 718 717 2861

Feel free to ask questions, clarifications, or discounts available when placing an order.
  +1 718 717 2861           + 44 161 818 7126           [email protected]
  +1 718 717 2861         [email protected]